By Brent Sohngen (sohngen.1@osu.edu)
Have you ever wondered who owns the trees? Historically, of course, most observers would agree the trees belong to the landowner who can do with them what they wish. However, because 50% of the wood dry matter in trees is composed of carbon, the answer to this question is set to become less clear under some new rules proposed by the World Resources Institute for their Greenhouse Gas Measurement Protocol.
This new protocol will govern how companies and people who own forestland count the carbon in their forests. WRI is proposing to use an approach that only counts carbon when a stand is cut, ignoring any carbon changes that happen in forests owned by people who do not cut some stands, but instead let them grow. This approach uses what is called a stand-by-stand no-harvesting counterfactual to measure the effect of wood harvesting.
Figure 1 illustrates how the approach works. A growing timber stand is accumulating carbon from time-period 1 to 15 and is then cut. There is a harvest emission, shown by the immediate reduction in carbon. The forest begins to regrow either through planting or natural regeneration. At some point down the road, depending on the species, the new stand will have as much carbon as the original stand would have had if left alone.
The idea of the no-harvest counterfactual is to assume the level of carbon in an unharvested forest follows the hatched line and calculate the emissions associated with the difference between harvesting and not harvesting that stand.
Figure 1: Stand-by-stand no-harvest counterfactual
There are many problems with this no-harvest counterfactual approach. Mostly it is wrong because all wood harvesting is done in mature stands, which only become mature because someone left them alone long enough to get older. The WRI GHG protocol ignores any of this growth (what happens before t=15 in the figure). It focuses solely on the harvesting event, failing to account for the observed fact that landowners hold many trees they do not harvest, plant trees on old farms, let trees regenerate naturally on pastures, hold trees instead of growing crops, grazing, or building subdivisions and box stores. There are real opportunity costs with holding trees, but the WRI GHG Protocol assumes all these activities, and the associated costs, are irrelevant.
So why do they propose this scientifically challenged approach? Here’s my take.
First, WRI doesn’t want to provide carbon-based incentives for companies to grow and cut trees, especially in planted stands. This was clear in an article WRI scientists published in Nature in 2023 and the opinion piece by two of the nation’s most esteemed ecologists in the same issue. The general idea of this approach is that any tree harvesting is bad, including the millions of cubic meters harvested every year for fuelwood uses by folks in developing countries.
This approach – sometimes known as Proforestation – misses fundamental economic realities associated not just with supply and demand for wood, but also with emerging carbon markets. Economic studies have shown that wood market incentives increase carbon in forests (Tian et al. 2018). They have also shown that efficient carbon policies would incentivize lots of avoided deforestation, lots of reforestation and afforestation, lots of avoided old growth harvesting, and lots of improved forest management often coming in the form of extended timber rotations (Sohngen and Mendelsohn, 2003; Austin et al, 2020; Favero et al., 2020).
In these studies, more wood harvesting happens with carbon incentives over time because more carbon in forests means there is also more wood to harvest. Increased supply in turn lowers wood prices. Intensive plantations make up only about 10-15% of the new area in forests, even with high carbon prices. The rest of the carbon gains are predicted to happen in natural forests, where compensation levels for carbon would be large enough to support significant efforts to ward off fires.
Second, WRI has an additionality problem. For decades, people in carbon markets have argued for a strong additionality test, whereby tons of carbon sequestered by companies in the timber business cannot be used to offset fossil carbon emissions because the trees were grown for timber not carbon. The additionality problem arises because WRI and others cannot reconcile an accounting standard that would let a company use tons generated on its own forest as an offset against its own emissions with an approach that does not allow those tons to be sold in carbon markets due to additionality.
Concern about additionality is understandable, but plenty of approaches have been developed to handle it, including following the advice of van Kooten et al. (1995).
Third, WRI is worried that more scientifically appropriate approaches – such as the standard of measuring changes in stocks over time like the US Forest Service does for the US as a whole – will confer benefits on landowners for carbon fertilization and climate change, which have elevated the stock of trees (Davis et al., 2023). It is completely accurate that measuring carbon gains with stock changes over the area owned will credit landowners for carbon gains that are partly attributed to carbon fertilization or climate change. This means that people who hold forests could receive carbon benefits 15-25% larger than otherwise because of carbon fertilization and climate change.
Far from being a liability, as WRI claims, this is exactly what we should want because it means landowners are adapting to climate and market incentives.
Paying for the benefits of carbon fertilization, or in the case of the GHG Protocol, including them in insets generated from a land-based inventory, is the correct approach precisely because it encourages efficient behavior with respect to the atmosphere by landowners.
Rather than leading to more emissions, incentives that embody carbon fertilization values would reduce deforestation, increase afforestation, increase reforestation, reduce fire risks, and increase forest rotation ages. A recent US EPA report found that carbon sequestration would be 28% greater under policy incentives when carbon fertilization benefits are part of the incentives rather than ignored (USEPA, 2024).
In conclusion, WRI’s proposed GHG Protocol approach is the wrong policy approach. If the approach were correct, it could be extended to all forests for carbon accounting, but it makes no more sense in aggregate than it does as applied to a specific forest operation. Ultimately, it aims to reduce the value of carbon embedded in forests, constituting a legal “taking” of a resource in the United States that is worth billions.
WRI seems to have concocted this no-harvest counterfactual approach simply to limit how forest-owning companies count the carbon gains they provide. But it doesn’t work. In contrast, the economic literature illustrates that carbon incentives based on IPCC carbon accounting will lead to more of all forests. WRI should use this far more efficient, and environmentally sound, approach.