Bush v. Gore in Historical Perspective

History teaches that, far from being a freakish anomaly, Bush v. Gore is just a particularly visible sign of a problematic phenomenon that is deep-rooted in our nation’s democracy.

The tenth anniversary of Bush v. Gore has not gone unnoticed. There have been personal reminiscences and reflections on its legacy, as well as renewed critiques (and defenses) of the Court’s decision. There has also been at least one academic symposium devoted to a decennial retrospective on the dispute over Florida’s presidential electors. I had the good fortune to participate in this symposium, sponsored by the St. Thomas Law Review, which featured some of the attorneys and public officials involved in the dispute, and I learned details that I had not known previously. (The symposium proceedings were recorded and, as I understand from the Review, will be made public for the benefit of scholarly research. Special kudos to Nate Persily for moderating, and helping the Review to plan the event.)

I want to observe the occasion by looking at Bush v. Gore from an historical perspective, which is also the approach I was asked to take for the St. Thomas symposium. Bush v. Gore is often considered, for better or worse, an anomaly or aberration. Linda Greenhouse has called it a “bad hair day.” Others have characterized it as truly or (if it is possible) especially unique—a situation never to be repeated—and therefore a case that would lack precedential value even if the Court had not explicitly cabined its Equal Protection holding.

I think history, however, sheds a different kind of light on Bush v. Gore. Far from being an anomaly, it is just a particularly recent and glaringly visible sign of a problematic phenomenon that is deeply rooted in our nation’s political culture. This problematic phenomenon concerns our democracy’s legal apparatus for major vote-counting disputes. It has two dimensions—one jurisprudential, the other institutional—and both combined to erupt in the judicial divisions that beset the Court in the case. The jurisprudential dimension is that, as a nation, we are torn between two different ways to view the constitutional right to vote, and we have been so torn from the beginning. One way is to emphasize the constitutional need to protect voters from wrongful disenfranchisement caused by the improper failure to count their particular ballots. The other way is to emphasize the constitutional need to protect the integrity of the voting-counting process from improper manipulation by government officials seeking to favor one of the candidates in the election. These two ways to view the constitutional right to vote can often be in tension with each other, yet both have equally longstanding status in our political pedigree (going all the way back to the Founding), and as a nation we have never attempted to prioritize between or otherwise reconcile the two. Consequently, when a vote-counting controversy emerges over the outcome of a presidential election, we are at sea on what “first principles” to invoke to think through the controversy. Partisans on either side easily can invoke whichever constitutional conception better suits their position in the particular controversy.

The institutional dimension to this problematic phenomenon is that as a nation we also do not know what institution of government we want to have final authority to resolve the jurisprudential debate over how the constitutional right to vote should resolve a particular vote-counting controversy. The Framers of the Constitution did not specify what institution has authority over a vote-counting dispute in a presidential election, and this particular omission is what led to the crisis of 1876 as well as Bush v. Gore. But the institutional uncertainty goes deeper than that. Precisely because the right to vote has a fundamental status in constitutional law (and has always been recognized as having such, even when at the outset the suffrage was significantly limited in scope), there has always been the potential that the judiciary considers as its prerogative the protection of this constitutional right as the judiciary itself thought fit. Moreover, once the Fourteenth Amendment federalized the protection of fundamental constitutional rights against wrongful deprivations by state governments, the institutional uncertainty compounded: now the federal, and not just the state, judiciary would see it as its business to protect the fundamental right to vote against state deprivations (although the federal judiciary’s conception of how best to protect the constitutional right to vote might differ from the state judiciary’s conception, with both conceptions plausible given the unresolved jurisprudential tensions in the context of vote-counting disputes).

I explore the origins of this problematic phenomenon, in both its dimensions, in a just-published piece in a symposium issue of the Indiana Law Review: The Founders’ Bush v. Gore: The 1792 Election Dispute and Its Continuing RelevanceThat piece explains how as a nation we got off on the wrong foot, so to speak, and why Bush v. Gore is just a recent and especially glaring misstep. The SSRN abstract of that piece gives a further summary.

But today, the tenth anniversary of the Supreme Court’s 5-4 stay of the statewide recount ordered by the 4-3 decision of the Florida Supreme Court, I want to focus on the particular institutional uncertainty of when the federal judiciary should exercise its supervisory powers over a state judicial system that arguably has contravened the constitutional right to vote in the context of a vote-counting dispute. The issue has no easy answer, which is why Bush v. Gore was an accident (or, for those who view it positively, an appropriate intervention) waiting to happen.

Bush v. Gore is a child, or grandchild, of Reynolds v. Sims, 377 U.S. 533 (1964). That truth is not merely the simplistic point that the majority in Bush v. Gore cited Reynolds as authority for its Equal Protection holding. Rather, Reynolds reoriented the federal judiciary’s relationship to state governments, including state courts, in terms of protecting the constitutional right to vote. In the post-Reynolds era, it is appropriate for the federal judiciary to insist that its conception of how best to protect the constitutional right to vote prevail over a contrary conception adopted by a state’s judiciary. We see this federal judicial attitude in the post-Reynolds decades bubbling beneath the surface in a myriad of lower-salience elections before it explodes in a presidential election in 2000. The most well-known of these harbingers of Bush v. Gore is Roe v. Alabama, which involved the election of Alabama’s Chief Justice.

Prior to Reynolds, the intellectual culture in which federal judges resided was hostile to the kind of comfortable intervention in state election vote-counting procedures that caused Bush v. Gore. This point is best seen by considering Lyndon Johnson’s victory in his 1948 U.S. Senate primary election. As detailed in Robert Caro’s biographical volume, Means of Ascent (part two of The Years of Lyndon Johnson), Johnson won that election because of intentionally fabricated vote totals. His opponent Coke Stevenson attempted to secure federal court intervention, to protect the constitutional right to vote under the Fourteenth Amendment, because in Stevenson’s judgment the state’s judiciary had been captured by pro-Johnson partisans and therefore was unable to serve as a fair and impartial tribunal. In this respect, Stevenson’s position was not dissimilar to Bush’s in 2000. Like Bush’s case, Stevenson’s case went all the way to the U.S. Supreme Court, and an emergency stay was issued, but in 1948 the purpose of the stay was the opposite of the purpose in Bush v. Gore: back then it was to divest the lower federal courts of jurisdiction on the ground that the federal judiciary could not invoke the Fourteenth Amendment to exercise supervisory authority over a state’s vote-counting procedures. As Caro recounts, Justice Hugo Black issued the stay after an unusual in-chambers oral argument, in which Abe Fortas served as Johnson’s lead lawyer. Had the Johnson-Stevenson disputed election occurred after Reynolds, the landscape would have looked entirely different: then Stevenson’s effort to secure federal court protection would have looked routine and compelling. Indeed, on its facts, the Stevenson-Johnson election presents an arguably even easier case for federal court intervention than Roe v. Alabama, 68 F.3d 404 (11th Cir. 1995), which is often taken as an example of when the federal court is right to find a Fourteenth Amendment violation in state vote-counting procedures.

I am not saying here which world is better: pre-Reynolds or post-Reynolds. My point, rather, is that they are so very different, and that we must understand Bush v. Gore as a product of the post-Reynolds world. Anyone who reads Caro’s book thinking that Stevenson was wronged, and wishing that the legal means would have been available to give him redress—means that would exist less than two decades later—must be prepared to accept that in 2000 the Supreme Court, in principle, had the proper authority to stop what it saw as a vote-counting process that had become hijacked by partisanship. Conversely, anyone who objects to the U.S. Supreme Court’s intervention in Bush v. Gore must be prepared to swallow the kind of outright electoral theft of a U.S. Senate election that was perpetrated in Texas in 1948, as portrayed meticulously by Caro, with no ability of the federal courts to intervene. If one is intellectually honest when considering these two celebrated cases, one cannot have it both ways.

As one ponders whether it is better to live in a pre-Reynolds or post-Reynolds world in this regard, consider this additional historical point. The first Justice John Marshall Harlan, often known as the “Great Dissenter” because of his clairvoyant dissent in Plessy v. Ferguson, also penned a dissent that anticipated the majority position in Bush v. Gore exactly 100 years later. The case was Taylor v. Beckham, 178 U.S. 548 (1900), and it involved a dispute over counting the ballots in a Kentucky gubernatorial election. The facts are ugly. One of the candidates was assassinated, and it appeared to many (including Justice Harlan) that the election was being stolen through fraudulent vote-counting. The victim of this apparent electoral theft, obtaining no relief from a reputedly partisan state judiciary, sought refuge in the U.S. Supreme Court. But this was the pre-Reynolds world, and the Court rejected the case on the same ground that Justice Black ruled in 1948: it is improper to invoke the Fourteenth Amendment as a basis for federal court supervision of a state vote-counting dispute. Justice Harlan, however, vigorously dissented. In language that would seem appropriate for a post-Reynolds world, he spoke of the necessity of federal court protection of the fundamental constitutional right to vote.

Here is just the finale of what Harlan wrote in his impassioned Taylor v. Beckham dissent:

“[T]he overturning of the public will, as expressed at the ballot box, . . . in order to accomplish partisan ends, is a crime against free government, and deserves the execration of all lovers of liberty. . . . I cannot believe the judiciary is helpless in the presence of such a crime. The person elected, as well as the people who elected him, have rights that the courts may protect. . . . I am of opinion that the writ of error should not have been dismissed, and that the [C]ourt should have adjudged that the decree below took from Taylor and Marshall rights protected by the 14th Amendment of the Constitution of the United States.”

Was Harlan wrong? He certainly was not wrong in Plessy even if he was alone at the time. But if Harlan was right in Taylor v. Beckman, then it is hard to say that Court’s December 9th stay in Bush v. Gore was institutionally inappropriate. If it is proper for federal courts to intervene when they think they see state courts tolerating, or even perpetrating, stolen elections, then the warrant exists for the majority in Bush v. Gore if they think that something of the kind is occurring. We can debate whether what the 4-3 decision of the Florida Supreme Court did amounted to a danger of electoral theft, but then we are back into the jurisprudential dimension of our longstanding problematic phenomenon: there is a genuine tension in a constitutional tradition about how best to handle the kind of vote-counting dispute that the Florida Supreme Court faced.

The truth is that we are unsettled regarding the institutional dimension as we are the jurisprudential dimension. As much as we inhabit the post-Reynolds world, we are ambivalent towards its full implications. We can read Harlan’s dissent in Taylor v. Beckham and be sympathetic, but we also fear overreaching by a federal judiciary. We don’t want to federalize every state vote-counting dispute, and in the ten years after Bush v. Gore we have not yet figured out where to draw the line. Indeed, we only somewhat recognize that any line drawn by the federal judiciary is one ultimately policed by the federal judiciary, and thus there is the inevitability of the federal judiciary having a general supervisory role in these cases even if we purport to limit the exercise of this federal power to a narrow subset of extreme instances.

Bush v. Gore came to us a century after Harlan’s dissent in Taylor v. Beckham and can be seen as the fulfillment of Harlan’s vision of a role for the U.S. Supreme Court to protect the constitutional right to vote, and to have one’s ballot counted fairly, from partisan abuse by state officials. Now ten years after Bush v. Gore, we can begin to see that case as on a historical continuum that starts with the Founding, extend through the Hayes-Tilden dispute of 1876 and on to Taylor v. Beckham at the end of the nineteenth century. A half-century later is the Stevenson-Johnson dispute, which is the culmination of the “no jurisdiction” view adopted by the Taylor v. Beckham majority before the pendulum begins to swing with the advent of Reynolds v. Sims.

Will the pendulum swing back again, because of antipathy to Bush v. Gore or otherwise? Or will we oscillate uncertainly in some kind of institutional “no man’s land,” not knowing what we think of the relationship between the state and federal judiciaries when it comes to vote-counting disputes? And will our institutional uncertainty continue to be compounded by jurisprudential uncertainty regarding the constitutional principles that should apply to these disputes? Unless as a nation we begin to grapple systematically with these two dimensions of uncertainty, I fear that Bush v. Gore, far from being an isolated aberration that we can easily forget, will instead be just our generation’s name for a perennial weakness in our system of democracy.

The Founders’ Bush v. Gore

Here is the SSRN abstract for my article, The Founders’ Bush v. Gore: The 1792 Election Dispute and Its Continuing Relevance, which I am honored to have included in the recent symposium published by the Indiana Law Review:

ABSTRACT:

In 1792, the Founders of our Republic and its Constitution faced their own version of what our generation knows as Bush v. Gore. It occurred in the context of that year’s election for governor in New York. John Jay was challenging the incumbent, and Jay and his supporters believed that they were wrongly robbed of their rightful victory when the state’s canvassing committee – in divided vote that fell along party-line lines – disqualified one county’s ballots because of a technical defect in the delivery of these ballots from the county to the Secretary of State.

Although the 1792 dispute concerned the rules for ballot delivery, rather than hanging or dimpled chads, the same basic jurisprudential debate in Bush v. Gore existed in 1792. Just as Gore argued for avoiding the disenfranchisement of voters as a consequence of faulty electoral machinery, so too did Jay’s side claim that protecting voters from the loss of their fundamental (and constitutional) right to the franchise was justification for excusing a technical breach of the state’s ballot delivery law. Conversely, just as Bush’s legal team claimed that strict enforcement of Florida’s election rules was necessary to preserve the integrity of the electoral process, so too did Jay’s opponents make the identical argument.

Moreover, this debate about how best to operate democracy in the context of a dispute over the results of an important statewide election consumed the attention of the Founding Generation. Jay’s Federalist Papers co-authors, Hamilton and Madison weighed in with their views, as did Jefferson, Monroe, and Burr. Other important, but less well-known, Founders were also involved. For example, Edmund Randolph, the nation’s first Attorney General, forcefully expounded the integrity argument. James Kent, a Jay supporter who would later be known as “America’s Blackstone” for his Commentaries on American Law, condemned the canvassing committee for being structurally biased against Jay’s side in its membership.

This largely forgotten historical episode, with its similarities to the disputed presidential election of 2000, is more than just an interesting curiosity. Rather, the difficulties that the Founding Generation had with its own version of Bush v. Gore – especially its lack of an institution for resolving the dispute that was perceived to be structurally fair to both sides – helps to explain why our own generation had such difficulty with resolving the 2000 presidential election. We have inherited the constitutional system that the Founders bequeathed to us. But that system did not include an adequate mechanism for handling a disputed election for chief executive, whether governor or president. This Article explores the reasons for the Founders’ inability to equip us, or (as shown by the events of 1792) even themselves, with this necessary element of a well-functioning constitutional democracy. As a nation, we will continue to suffer from this inadequacy until we recognize that the Founders did not give us all that we need and thus we take it upon ourselves to add the missing institutional ingredient to the system they gave us.

Minnesota Supreme Court Settles Reconciliation Issue

The dispute over reconciliation in the state’s gubernatorial election is over, but the court points out an issue that could prove troublesome in future close elections.  UPDATE: The Republican candidate has now conceded.

In a unanimous, thorough, and well-reasoned opinion, the Minnesota Supreme Court rules that voter receipts, and not just poll book signatures, may be used for purposes of reconciliation.  This ruling has the effect of eliminating the basis on which Republican Tom Emmer had attempted to challenge reconciliation practices in this year’s election.  Unless Emmer has some other grounds for contesting the election that is not publicly apparent, it would seem that his Democratic opponent Mark Dayton’s victory is a foregone conclusion.  

Still, buried in footnote 4 of the court’s opinion is an unsettled legal issue of potential interest in future elections.  There the court noted that, even though the use of voter receipts is proper, the remains the question of what happens if the number of voter receipts does not match up with the number of ballots cast.  As I noted in a previous post, and as the court itself quoted, the relevant statute calls for the local election officials to randomly withdraw a number of ballots equal to the excess number of ballots cast.  But apparently this statutory requirement is not uniformly followed among election officials in Minnesota.  The court stated:  “In responses filed to the petition, certain local election officials appear to have conceded that they are not removing excess ballots, although they do not concede a statutory violation.”  The court went on to say that it did not need to address the propriety of this local practice, because Emmer’s complaint had focused specifically on the issue of receipts.

It seems beyond the realm of possibility that any failure to follow the statutory requirement of random withdrawal could affect the outcome of this year’s gubernatorial election in Minnesota.  But, as the state supreme court itself has now warned, this issue is there potentially lurking for future elections.  If Minnesota again had an election as close as its 2008 U.S. Senate election, where the margin was just 200 or 300 votes, I presume the state would not want to be in a position where it faced ferocious litigation over the apparent noncompliance with this statutory requirement by election officials in some localities but not others.   That would be a headache that might cause Minnesota to relive the kind of fight that it faced in 2008.  For this reason, it behooves election administrators in Minnesota to ask themselves whether they can take steps to coordinate their local practices with the state’s statutory requirements, so as to avoid this potential situation.

UPDATE (Dec. 8): The Republican candidate for governor, Tom Emmer, has now conceded.  This concession, coming well in advance of the January 3 inauguration date for the state’s new governor, shows that Minnesota was able to bring this disputed election to a successful conclusion.  There was perhaps more saber-rattling this year than the roughly 9000-vote margin of victory would seem to have warranted.  Speculation was that ardent Republicans wanted to use a dispute over the outcome to delay the inauguration of Democrat Mark Dayton, to keep Republican incumbent Tim Pawlenty in office as a holdover for as long as possible.  But in his concession speech, Emmer dismissed use of election litigation for purposes of delay as inapproriate.  Having dodged that possibility this year, Minnesota now can take a collective deep breath and more leisurely consider what risk it may face in the future of such delay tactics and other potential vulnerabilities, including the one identified earlier in this post about the random withdrawal procedure.  Having suffered through an eight-month disputed U.S. Senate election in 2008, many observers in Minnesota wanted to avoid a dispute this time that went into January.   The state accomplished this objective today, but it can still ask itself whether it has the right set of procedures and institutions in place to achieve the same objective if a future gubernatorial election has an apparent margin of victory in the hundreds rather than in the thousands.

A Note on Reconciliation in Minnesota

It looks as is if, going forward, “reconciliation” will be the main issue in the still-unresolved gubernatorial election in Minnesota.  This post discusses Minnesota law on reconciliation and how it might play out in this year’s election.

In a news conference this morning, Republican gubernatorial candidate Tom Emmer made clear that he is not conceding the race to his opponent Mark Dayton (who leads by approximately 9000 ballots) unless and until Emmer is satisfied on the issue of reconciliation.

What exactly is reconciliation and why is Emmer presently unsatisfied?

Reconciliation is the process by which election officials match the number of voters who cast ballots with the number of ballots cast. In Minnesota, as in some other states, if when preparing to make their initial count of the ballots, local officials find that there are more ballots cast than the number of voters who cast them, these officials are supposed to perform a procedure known as “random withdrawal”: literally, an official is supposed to reach into the ballot box, without looking specifically, and pull out the number of excess ballots.  [In Minnesota, this process occurs on Election Night at the precincts.]

Minnesota’s statute is clear about this requirement: section 204C.20, subdivision 2 (entitled “excess ballots”) details several steps that must occur in the reconciliation process. First, the officials see if any excess ballots were not properly authenticated in advance. If so, these specific ballots are removed and not counted. (If there is no excess to begin with, then these ballots not properly authenticated may still be counted.) After this step is complete: “If there is still an excess of properly [authenticated] ballots, the election judges shall replace them in the box, and one election judge, without looking, shall withdraw from the box a number of ballots equal to the excess. The withdrawn ballots shall not be counted.”

In Minnesota this year, the fight over reconciliation has focused on so far the exact procedures used to conduct the reconciliation process.  The debate has been whether it is permissible to count the number of receipts that voters receive before casting their ballots, as specified by administrative regulation, or instead the process must be confined to what the statute terms as either “the number of signed voter’s certificates” or “the number of names entered in the election register.”  This post, however, focuses not on that issue, but instead on the potential issue of random withdrawal itself.  The inquiry here is whether any failure to perform random withdrawal, after it is settled what counting method is appropriate for reconciliation, could be the basis for litigation over the outcome of an election.  It is an issue that I have explored in previous scholarship.  See Edward B. Foley, The Analysis and Mitigation of Electoral Errors: Theory, Practice, Policy 350, 365-369 (2007).

It is likely that compliance or noncompliance with random withdrawal will fizzle out as a practical matter in connection with this year’s governor’s election in Minnesota.  That’s because, as discussed further at the end of this post, it is extraordinarily unlikely that the number of ballots that should have been withdrawn but were not would be anywhere near enough to make a difference in this race.  Still, absent seeing the actual final evidence on what those numbers are, and thinking about what might happen if Minnesota pulls a trifecta and has another statewide election in 2012 that is close enough to fight about (or if a similar issue should arise in another state), it is worth exploring what might happen if noncompliance with random withdrawal conceivably might have made a difference in a close election.

Allegedly, in this year’s election, some local officials in Minnesota did not perform the random withdrawal procedure, as required by statute. In the past, there has been an indication emerging from research into election administration practices that some officials philosophically don’t like this requirement; they view it as antiquated and contrary to the interests of the voters they serve. These officials believe that they can be confident in the legitimacy of the excess ballots cast even if they cannot be completely reconciled with corresponding evidence of the voter who cast the ballot.  One hears of poll workers saying something along the lines of, “Well, I know Jane Smith voted because she’s a neighbor and I saw her cast her ballot, so even if she did not sign the register and it appears that we are short one voter, we shouldn’t randomly draw one ballot from our precinct, because the extra ballot must be Jane’s.” [Indeed, one local election official was quoted in the Pioneer Press: “You have to remember that I’m in outstate Minnesota where we all know each other. . . .  The wife signs and the husband doesn’t and off they go.”]  One can be sympathetic with the position of the poll worker in this situation, but failure to perform random withdrawal when there remains a discrepancy between the number of ballots and the statutorily acceptable evidence of number of voters does not strictly comply with the requirements of Minnesota’s statutory law.

Minnesotans, of course, have heard this kind of thing before—recently, in the context of their disputed 2008 U.S. Senate election. Back then, the issue was the rules for submitting absentee ballots. It turned out that some election officials liked to be lenient in the enforcement of those rules as well, for the benefit of the voter. Some voters would fail to fill out their absentee ballot envelopes properly, but the officials would still count them if they were confident that the voters and their ballots were valid anyway. In the litigation over the outcome of the Senate race, the courts took a dim view of this administrative leniency: the statutory rule must be strictly followed whether the local officials like it or not. Something similar may happen with respect to the random withdrawal issue this year.

The leading case in Minnesota on the obligation to follow the random withdrawal statute properly is Johnson v. Trnka, 277 Minn. 468, 154 N.W.2d 185 (1967). There, the trial court mistakenly performed the random withdrawal procedure without first removing ballots that were not properly authenticated. Because there were more of these ballots (6) than the excess over the number of voters (2), removing these ballots eliminated the excess and there was no longer a warrant for random withdrawal. The Minnesota Supreme Court, accordingly, reversed.

Earlier in the current fight over the governor’s election, Emmer’s side asked the Minnesota Supreme Court to mandate compliance with the random withdrawal procedure before beginning the mandatory statewide administrative recount of all initially counted ballots. The high court declined to do this, but has not yet stated its reasons. In his press conference, Emmer said he is waiting for the court’s opinion before deciding to make his next move on the reconciliation issue.

The Johnson precedent, because its particular facts involved a different problem, does not specifically say what happens if (after discounting ballots that were not properly authenticated), there still remains an excess number of ballots relative to the number of voters, but the local officials did not perform random withdrawal. In a post-recount judicial contest of a certified gubernatorial election, may the losing candidate demand that the court order the statutorily required random withdrawal? The tenor of the Johnson opinion, indicating that the statute should be followed properly, suggests maybe so. But it is hardly a foreordained conclusion.

For one thing, the judicial precedent in other states is that random withdrawal will not be ordered subsequently in a contest of an election if local election officials can offer good reasons for not conducting the procedure. For example, in Minnesota’s neighbor Wisconsin, that state’s supreme court has held an excess ballot, even if not properly authenticated, should not be removed from the count unless there is separate evidence that it was cast by an unqualified voter. Ollmann v. Kowalewski, 238 Wis. 574, 300 N.W. 183 (1941). That court stated: “It is more likely that the election clerks made a mistake in checking someone who voted . . . . The ballot expressed the will of the person who voted it. To reject it without proof of illegality or fault on his part would disfranchise the voter.” This Wisconsin approach is the opposite of the strict compliance standard embraced by the Minnesotsa Supreme Court in the Coleman v. Franken litigation. But Minnesota’s high court there made a point of saying that the strict compliance standard for absentee voting rules did not necessarily apply to in-precinct voting rules, for which Minnesota apparently adopts a more lenient posture. Thus, the choice between strict and lenient enforcement of the specific random withdrawal rule potentially at issue in this year’s gubernatorial election still seems an open question under the state’s judicial precedents.

Finally, there remains the all-important question of numbers. Assuming that Dayton’s certified victory at the end of the recount is 9000 (to use a round number), presumably Emmer would need to show at least 9001 excess ballots statewide in order to even begin to engage the court with the question of whether to order any random withdrawal that should have occurred but didn’t. Even assuming that Emmer could show a much larger lack of reconciliation—say, 90,000 excess ballots statewide, to jump an order of magnitude above Dayton’s margin of victory—it would seems extraordinarily improbable that performing random withdrawal would overturn that victory. I’m no statistician but my understanding is that those who are would calculate the odds as infinitesimal that randomly removing 90,000 ballots from a certified count of 2.1 million ballots would erase a 9000-vote margin. In this circumstance, then, it is quite possible that the Minnesota judiciary would not put the state’s election officials to the time and expense of performing the random withdrawal procedure where there is no reasonable possibility of changing the outcome of the election.

Still, assuming that random withdrawal did not occur this year in Minnesota as required–an allegation that (as far as I can tell) has not yet been definitely established–one wonders whether it would have been possible to avoid any of these legal issues on what if anything to do to remedy such a shortcoming.  Perhaps if the election officials had just performed random withdrawal as required by the statute, rather than attempting to improve on the administration of the electoral process according to their own lights (assuming for the moment that any such behavior occurred in Minnesota this year), any potential legal issue regarding compliance with the random withdrawal rule could have been avoided. If the statute on random withdrawal needs to be reformed, that is a task for the legislature to take up. Just as with updating antiquated rules for absentee voting, problems emerge if local officials deviate from the existing rules on their own, rather than getting the rules fixed for everyone statewide.

[Updated December 5, 2010]

Looking Backward: Instant Runoff Voting in the 2010 Midterm Elections

By Kevin Oles

In some states, the recent midterm elections are far from over. However, in those races where the winners have been determined, these election results are a veritable goldmine of data. Continuing my interest in exploring alternative voting systems, looking at this data through the lens of Instant Runoff Voting (IRV) illuminates three conclusions: (1) how IRV would affect elections if broadly implemented; (2) that there are differences in voting efficiency between IRV and plurality voting; and (3) putting economics and broad application together, it is possible to answer the ultimate question of IRV: “is it better than plurality voting?” For brevity, my previous commentary on IRV walks through the basic mechanisms of the voting system.

Organizing the data of the midterm elections, the elections coalesce around three categories of results when examining them under IRV system design:

1.Races in which no candidate received a majority of votes

2.Races in which a candidate received a slim majority of votes

3.Races in which a candidate received a large majority of votes

Working backwards through these groups, Category 3 is the easiest to understand, and plentiful examples exist: Wyoming’s gubernatorial race: Meade received 123,764 votes and the next closest challenger, Peterson, received 43,336 votes; in Hawaii’s Senate election Inouye received 276,928 votes and his closest challenger had 79,830 votes. These Category 3 races, if run under IRV, would result in the same winner without IRV affecting the results. Category 3 elections indicate that even with widespread implementation of IRV, the elections that experts and pundits expect to be landslides are in fact landslides. IRV would not cause drastic, dramatic voting shifts and change “safe” elections different from those results obtained in plurality voting.

Category 2 races are those with a clear winner, but that winner achieved a very small majority of votes. This type of election is where the differences between IRV and plurality voting start to arise, as IRV could produce different winners in these races because of differences between voting system structures. IRV produces two effects that plurality voting dampens: (1) voters do not feel pressure to vote for a candidate from either major party candidates as they might otherwise feel that their vote wasted; and (2) votes can aggregate in later runoff rounds for a candidate that survives each successive round but does not achieve any sort of numerical strength and becomes electorally strong. Looking at the result of the Colorado gubernatorial election illustrates these effects.

John Hickenlooper 856,569 50.7%

Tom Tancredo 620,626 36.8%

Dan Maes 187,998 11.1%

Jaimes Brown 12,337 0.7%

Other Candidates (2) 11,183 0.7%

First, if individuals favored Maes and disliked either Tancredo or Hickenlooper, in plurality voting these voters would feel pressured to vote for the candidate in the best position to defeat their disliked candidate and not vote for their actual first choice candidate. Thus, it seems that a candidate wins under plurality voting because a significant number of voters support the candidate, but also because voters do not like the opposing major party candidate (Delaware’s Senate race might be an illustration of this principle). IRV enables voters to choose their actual first choice because there is no pressure that voters will “waste” their vote by not voting against the disliked candidate by having to select a candidate with a higher possibility to win. Then, under IRV, an individual like Maes or Tancredo can receive a majority in later runoff voting rounds by aggregating second, third, and fourth round votes when voters do not feel pressured to support a top two candidate.

In Category 1 elections, IRV requires further runoff rounds in order to declare a winner. For example, the Florida Senate election was very close, and under a system in which a candidate must earn a majority to win, the ultimate result can be far different. In Florida Rubio received a near majority, but as votes aggregate, another voter could overtake that lead. Consider the results of Florida’s Senate election as the starting point for this next hypothetical:

Election Round 1 Votes Percentage

Marco Rubio 2,615,262 48.9%

Charlie Crist 1,588,821 29.7%

Kendrick B. Meek 1,076,028 20.1%

Other candidates (6) 39, 409 0.7% (approx.)

As there is no majority on the first ballot, further rounds are necessary. There are a number of candidates in this election who received approximately 0.1% of the total votes, so several runoff cycles are necessary to eliminate these low-vote receiving candidates. Thus, after eight rounds of this hypothetical runoff, Crist and Meek have made minor gains while Rubio stands in front.

Election Round 8 Votes Percentage

Marco Rubio 2,615,262 48.9%

Charlie Crist 1,627,773 30.6%

Kendrick B. Meek 1,090, 501 20.5%

In this round, Meek is eliminated and the ninth round is a head to head between Crist and Rubio. Voters who placed Meek first in this hypothetical placed Crist second and thus Crist earns a majority and wins the election with 51.1% of votes.

Election Round 9 Votes Percentage

Marco Rubio 2,615,262 48.9%

Charlie Crist 2,718,274 51.1%

It is possible to imagine the election turning in a different direction under slightly changed voting results. Rubio needed to aggregate approximately 44,499 votes to earn a majority, but the first eight rounds do not encompass enough available votes for Rubio to win even if he picked up every vote as the second choice candidate after the minor candidates are eliminated. Thus, in the eighth round, favoring Rubio in each runoff cycle the vote would be:

Election Round 8 (Version 2) Votes Percentage

Marco Rubio 2,653,671 49.8%

Charlie Crist 1,588,821 29.7%

Kendrick B. Meek 1,076, 028 20.1%

Once Meek is eliminated and the ninth round runoff begins, Rubio only has to pick up 6,089 voters to earn a majority and win the race.

Drawing a greater point from these three categories of elections, we see results that can best be understood through economic thinking. We have already seen that IRV allows a clear winner when the electorate votes in clear favor of a candidate and removes some obstacles tow voters being able to vote without external pressures. Additionally, IRV creates the possibility that in marginal cases, non top-two candidates can win, inducing more competition.

In purely economic terms, efficiency occurs when no individual can be made better off without harming another individual. Modeling from economic efficiency, voting efficiency then occurs when no voter or candidate can be made better off without harming another voter or candidate. Measuring voting systems in terms of comparative efficiency demonstrates the differences in externalities and encumbrances of different voting systems. Of course, a voting system that is “maximally efficient” is not necessarily a good thing—for instance, when voters have no encumbrance to voting, vote fraud might be rampant due to the ease of submitting a ballot; when candidates have no encumbrances on their actions, the ballot may be flooded with similar candidates such that choosing amongst them is near impossible.

Comparing IRV and plurality voting, both appear to hit a similar point of voting efficiency. As seen earlier, Category 1 and 2 elections demonstrate that IRV voters have less external pressures on their voting behavior and candidates have fewer barriers to enter the election market. However, plurality voting is more efficient in education, as IRV forces voters to educate themselves about a far larger group of candidates because these voters must later rank the candidates. Voters must learn enough about each candidate to rank them against the rest of the field, and if voters do not rank candidates or learn enough, the primary value of IRV is defeated. Additionally, on the candidate side, plurality system provide better screening and vetting mechanisms for candidates when considering the primary and general elections—the barriers to entry that plurality voting possesses serves to exclude possible candidates who have no business in the election market.

Tying together the election data with what we see in comparing voting efficiency sheds light on the question of “which is better, IRV or plurality voting?” The answer has become clear: there is not some quantitatively better system, but IRV and plurality voting stress different values in the composition of their systems. The question then, in considering whether to continue with plurality voting or to move to IRV, changes to “what values do we want our voting systems to reflect?” Answering this question then, we must consider whether we value our top-two candidate system (favoring plurality voting), or whether we think attempting to select through majority voting is more important (favoring IRV). The answer to this valuation, then, seems best left to voters.

The 2010 Statewide Ballot Issues

By Dale A. Oesterle

The November election had 160 statewide ballot measures before voters. There were numerous local measures on ballots as well, of course. The results are not all in (nine are too close to call), but there is much to say about those results that are final.

First, the decline of the political party “wedge” measure and the upsurge of the legislative referrals. Of the 160 measures, state legislatures referred 113 (up from 2008) to the voters, and citizens initiated 42 (down from 2008). Excluding those too close to call, voters approved 73 percent of the referenda and only 43 percent of the initiatives.

Legislative referenda can be either voluntary( the legislature puts the measure to voters), or involuntary( the citizens force a vote on a legislative act without the legislature’s consent). Many were voluntary. Legislatures were asking citizens to approve structural changes in the election process or government offices. Few referenda gave citizens the final say on difficult social questions.

There were, in addition to the normal statewide bonding proposals, measures to rename the office of secretary of state, abolish the office of treasurer, change the due date for initiatives, change the signatures need for initiatives, structure redistricting procedures, set state legislature size, establish internal majority voting requirements and meeting times, create an ethics commission, and eliminate a state’s public campaign finance option. Maryland came within a hair’s breadth of approving a new constitutional convention.

In 2000 and 2004, commentators were nervous about political party involvement in ballot measures. Political parties were putting controversial citizen initiatives on the ballot to incentivize their core voters. Since initiative procedural hurdles are difficult for grass-roots groups but not problem for political parties (who are already organized on the ground in every county), commentators worried about the initiative process “being hijacked” by political parties. This year saw few true “wedge” issues on the ballot.

Second, the citizens successful in putting measures on the ballots were (with one major exception), more often than not, pushing views on causes not accepted by their legislatures. There were measures to roll back global warming legislation, to define a “person” to include a fetus, to prohibit state courts from relying on international or sharia law, to legalize marijuana, and to block the new federal health care legislation. The exception was measures in seven states aimed at improving the lot of military veterans. All passed.

Third, the difficult economic conditions manifested themselves in the results. States asked for less bonding authorization in an even-year election than they have in many years. Ninety percent of the requests passed, however. In multiple states (both red and blue), voters rejected every revenue increase on the ballot. In one state, Washington, the voters repealed the 2009 state tax increases passed by the legislature. A Massachusetts measure to cut the state sales tax rate by more than half failed, however. Voters in Colorado rejected initiatives that would have fixed an allocation of state funding to education.

Fourth, the national press focused on two propositions, California’s Proposition 19 to legalize marijuana and Oklahoma’s Measure 25 that prohibits state courts from relying on Sharia or international law in deciding cases. National press pundits lost on both, with Proposition 19 failing and Measure 25 winning. Proposition 19 was ahead in the polls until the very last week or so before the election.

Now the press is piling on Oklahoma. The national press consensus is that the Measure reflects both ignorance and bigotry. Oklahoma citizens do not think so. They have rejected the approach of Great Britain (and other western countries) that have established sharia courts to settle certain disputes among Muslims. And they also rejected the tendency of Supreme Court Justices Stevens and Ginsberg (and supported the opposition of Justice Scalia) to cite foreign law to shape their opinions in United States cases. For the citizens of Oklahoma to weigh in on such issues seems pretty well-informed to me.

The Election of 1960 Fifty Years Later

By David Stebenne

November 8, 2010 marks the fiftieth anniversary of the presidential election of 1960, which still very much interests those who care about disputed elections and how best to resolve them. The clearest sign of that continuing interest is the steady stream of new scholarly books on that subject. Some of the most recent include Gary A. Donaldson’s The First Modern Campaign: Kennedy, Nixon, and the Election of 1960 (Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield, 2007); William J. Rorabaugh, The Real Making of the President: Kennedy, Nixon and the 1960 Election (Lawrence: University Press of Kansas, 2009); and Edmund F. Kallina, Jr., Kennedy v. Nixon: The Presidential Election of 1960 (Gainesville: University Press of Florida, 2010).

Why, one may wonder, does all this serious scholarly attention still get paid to a single electoral contest that ended half a century ago without (in marked contrast to Bush v. Gore in 2000) much in the way of recounts or lawsuits? There are several reasons for this. The 1960 presidential election was the first in which television can fairly be said to have been central to the result. By that year, most American homes had TV’s for the first time. Richard Nixon’s decision to accept John Kennedy’s proposal for televised presidential debates meant that for the first time both major-party candidates appeared for a sustained period together on TV once it had become the nation’s dominant medium of mass communication. The novelty of this in 1960 produced very high rates of viewership, thereby making the election memorable and altering its outcome. Simply put, this form of “free media” provided the oxygen for Kennedy’s presidential bid that fall. Before the first televised presidential debate on September 26th most polls showed him behind. After it, most showed him ahead, a pattern that continued through Election Day.

The impact of televised debates also showed immediately on the campaign trail. Following the first debate, the size of Kennedy’s crowds roughly doubled. Even more noticeable was the change in energy. Prior to the first debate, the mood among onlookers at most Kennedy rallies had been friendly but no more. After the first debate, Kennedy campaign appearances acquired the kind of energy and enthusiasm one associates with an appearance in 1960 of a rock and roll star. Journalists assigned to cover his appearances came up with new terms to describe the behavior of Kennedy’s young female fans. There were the “jumpers,” who began jumping up and down as his car approached, the “double jumpers”, who were pairs (usually sisters or friends) who jumped in unison while holding hands, and the “runners” who broke through the restraining line and pursued his car on foot.

The sharp increase in the size of Kennedy’s crowds and their enthusiasm ultimately mattered because it motivated Kennedy campaign volunteers to work very hard and thus to drive up turnout among Democratic-leaning voters, in the nation’s biggest metropolitan areas especially. The reaction to Kennedy’s appearance in the televised debates also motivated most Democratic leaders, such as the heads of the urban machines, the chieftains of organized labor and the Southern governors, to work hard for his election. No one understood all that more than Kennedy himself. When asked after the election how he had managed to defeat Nixon, Kennedy replied crisply “television.”

A second reason for the excitement then and interest later was the simple fact of Kennedy’s Catholicism, which broke an unofficial but still very significant “rule” of the American political system as it was in those days. Until Kennedy won in 1960, the sense of most knowledgeable people was that only a white, male, Protestant could realistically aspire to serve as the head of the American government. Even many of Kennedy’s liberal supporters firmly believed that, such as United Auto Workers union chief Walter Reuther, who had argued passionately during the 1960 primaries that no Catholic could be elected because anti-Catholic prejudice among Baptist and Methodist Democrats was too strong. A lot of older American Catholics with bad memories of Al Smith’s presidential campaign in 1928 felt the same way. All that earlier effort had seemingly accomplished was to stir up anti-Catholic sentiment to no positive result; why go through the same thing all over again, many of them thought to themselves, and sometimes said out loud. For Kennedy’s Catholic supporters in particular, the real “Massachusetts miracle” was not that state’s economic comeback in the 1980’s but rather Kennedy’s victory in 1960, which altered assumptions about who could realistically hope to hold high public office in the United States and paved the way for the next person who was not a white, male, Protestant to win: Barack Obama in 2008. Kennedy’s victory, like Obama’s, also serves as a source of encouragement to many of those in the over seventy percent of the American population that is not white, male and Protestant.

A third reason for the continuing scholarly interest in the presidential election of 1960, closely related to the TV and Catholicism factors, was that the outcome was an upset. Until the televised debates, most knowledgeable observers of the American political scene had assumed that Nixon would ultimately prevail. Yes, Kennedy was young, handsome, well-spoken and had a lot of family money behind him, the pundits acknowledged. For those reasons, he would make the contest interesting, it was quietly thought, but in the end come up short, thanks to the extraordinarily broad popularity of Eisenhower-era Republicanism, with which Nixon and his running mate (U.S. Ambassador to the United Nations Henry Cabot Lodge) were closely identified. Thus, as the 1960’s opened, the prevailing view among the experts was that Republicans would retain the White House and the country probably would not change very much. Kennedy’s surprising victory helped alter that situation.

As important as those three factors are in explaining continued interest in the 1960 presidential election, others have intensified that curiosity. That electoral contest was truly remarkable in that it was both the closest of the twentieth century and the one with the highest turnout ever. Kennedy’s margin of victory in the popular vote worked out to an average of one half of one vote per precinct nationwide, which is as close to a tie as we are likely ever to see. Even more striking was the high turnout. The most meaningful measure is the fraction of the adult population that cast ballots, and in 1960 that figure was the highest ever recorded. The national average was approximately 63.5%, but that figure is misleading in one important respect. On Election Day in 1960, the Jim Crow system still existed in the South and the Border States. That system’s barriers to voting (poll taxes, literacy tests, intimidation and all the rest) seriously depressed voting in at least fifteen states. In the other thirty-five, however, turnout was typically well above the national average. For example, in Franklin County, Ohio (where this commentary was written and published), the home of the state’s capital city (Columbus), voter registration as a percentage of all adults reached an all-time high in 1960, as did turnout: an astonishing 83% of all registered voters.

The closeness of the election combined with the record turnout to put the maximum possible strain on the nation’s electoral apparatus, and ultimately led to problems in election administration. Those problems have also fueled continuing scholarly interest in the 1960 presidential election because of the difficulty in determining whether Kennedy really won through honest means or corrupt ones. Excessive partisanship on both sides has complicated that analysis. The first account of the election, Theodore White’s classic entitled The Making of the President 1960 (New York: Atheneum, 1961) was written by a Kennedy partisan. The second account, the part of Richard Nixon’s memoir entitled Six Crises (Garden City: Doubleday, 1962) that dealt with the election, was even more biased in favor of Nixon. Those two accounts helped create a partisan kind of debate on a serious issue, which has clouded clear thinking ever since.

Scholarly analysis of the question of how Kennedy won has focused, quite rightly, on administration of the electoral process in two crucial states: Illinois and Texas. Kennedy ultimately was credited with the electoral votes of both, which gave him victory in the Electoral College tally. The problem with answering the question of how he prevailed there is twofold in nature. In Illinois, the most recent and fair-minded study (Kallina’s Kennedy v. Nixon) concludes that sufficient evidence does not exist to determine whether Chicago’s Democratic machine stole more votes there than Republicans did downstate. Texas presents a different kind of problem. A system of free and fair elections in the modern sense had not yet taken hold on the ground there in 1960. Voter fraud was fairly common, safeguards to prevent it were few, and 1960 was no different in those respects. Thus, the most dispassionate analysis of this issue from the perspective of fifty years later is that we will never know whether Kennedy really “won,” in the sense of what result an entirely honest and effective administration of the electoral process in Illinois and Texas would have produced on Election Day in 1960.

But if Kennedy’s victory in a legal sense remains forever clouded, in a political sense there was no doubt, then or afterward. The GOP was much the weaker of the two parties nationally in 1960. In order for its presidential candidate to win then, he had to do so clearly or not at all. Those at the top of the nation’s political system understood that hard fact. Compounding that sense of a decisive outcome politically if not legally was that most leading Republicans privately blamed Nixon’s own mistakes, not Democratic cheating in Illinois and Texas, for his defeat. Even his own running mate thought so. Most decisive on that score was the attitude of outgoing Republican President Dwight Eisenhower. By Election Day Eisenhower had become certain of a Nixon loss and deeply angry with him for the way he had run his campaign. Eisenhower had urged Nixon not to debate Kennedy, predicting correctly that such extensive television exposure would ultimately help the lesser known Democrat. Nixon compounded that mistake in the eyes of Eisenhower and other leading Republicans by failing to prepare properly for the debates, which left him feeling and looking weak and tired for the crucial first one.

It was this divergence between legal and political factors more than anything else that explains why there was no Bush v. Gore type dispute after Election Day in 1960. Law and politics are closely related, but they are not the same. For Nixon to have mounted an effective legal challenge afterward, the two major parties in Illinois, Texas and nationally would have had to be in better balance, and his own leading supporters would have had to believe that Nixon had run the better campaign and so been robbed. Thus, the outcome in 1960 has had longer-term implications for disputed elections, but not very obvious ones to most students of that episode. The resulting confusion continues to drive research, discussion and debate, with no end in sight.

 

Echoes of New York’s “Stolen Senate”?

As we watch events unfold this year concerning the unsettled control of the state senate in New York, and the several elections on which that control depends, let’s hope that the current resolution contains nothing like the ugliness that afflicted a similar episode in 1891.

Thanks to the sleuthing of Justin Levitt, I now know that control of the state senate in New York depends on the outcome of three undecided races. The New York Times has the details.

Of course, it is still extremely early in the process, and no one knows how it will turn out, but the basic facts bear some resemblance to one of the lowest moments in New York’s electoral history. During an episode known as “The Stolen Senate” (as described in Chapter XXX of this book), partisanship ran amok in 1891 when control of the state senate similarly depended on the outcome of several close and disputed elections.

The historical details are too convoluted and technical to describe in this “blog” post. My co-author Steve Huefner and I will cover it more in depth in the book on the history of disputed elections in the U.S., which we are currently writing. But the following brief synopsis, necessarily oversimplified for present purposes, will give you a flavor of what happened.

Back then, although four state senate seats were disputed, the fight ultimately boiled down to just two of them. If the Republicans prevailed in either of these two elections, they would control the state senate. The partisan split in the chamber was 15-14 in the Republican’s favor with only these two seats unresolved. Conversely, if the Democrats prevailed in both, they would have control.

One issue, involving Onondaga County (where Syracuse is located), concerned an error made by local election officials: they sent the official ballots designated for one precinct to another precinct by mistake. This election was one of the first in New York involving the so-called “Australian” ballots, in which the officials were responsible for printing and distributing them. Evidently, being unfamiliar with this responsibility, the election officials had trouble in its implementation. As a practical matter, however, the error did not prevent voters for making a choice in their local senate election: even though these voters received the ballot for the wrong precinct, the name of their senate candidates was on the ballot, and they were thus able to use the incorrect ballot to make their choice.

Based on the returns, if these ballots were counted, the Republican candidate for this seat would win. Not surprisingly, the Democrats challenged these ballots on the ground that they were improper under the state’s new election law adopting the Australian ballot. In a 4-3 vote of the state’s highest court, the Democrats prevailed on this argument. The judges in the majority happened to be all Democrats, and they adopted a “strict compliance” standard for the new Australian ballot statute. The dissenters, two Republicans and one Democrat, argued vociferously for an interpretation of the statute that would prevent the disenfranchisement of innocent voters as a result of official error. “Assuming that [the statute] is susceptible to two constructions—one preserving the right of the voter, and the other forfeiting it—can it be doubtful which construction ought to prevail?” The dissenting position was a version of what Rick Hasen calls “the Democracy Canon” of statutory construction for disputed election cases, but that position did not carry the day, arguably due the partisanship of the majority in that case (although of course the judges in the majority articulated what they claimed were important policy justifications for strict enforcement of the new anti-fraud protections of the Australian ballot).

This 4-3 judicial victory in the Onondaga County seat brought the Democrats to a 15-15 tie in the state senate.

The resolution of the other outcome-determinative disputed election, in Dutchess County (where Poughkeepsie and other Hudson River Valley communities are located), was even more troubling. This dispute also concerned the new Australian ballots, but a different type of problem. Here, the problem was essentially a smudge that the printing process had left on the ballots. The Democrats claimed that these smudges were identifying marks that invalidated the ballots. If these ballots were invalidated, the Democratic candidate again would prevail. But this argument was too much for any of the Democrats on the state’s highest court, which unanimously ordered the certification of returns showing that the Republican had prevailed. (Because of the complicated judicial procedures involved in the case, and the posture in which it arrived at the court, the order was technically for the certification to occur once it arrived from the county to the Secretary of State.) The state canvassing board, which was controlled by the Democrats, however, refused to obey this judicial decree. Instead, the board certified a return that excluded the disputed ballots, and on the basis of this certification, the Democrats took control of the state senate. (They accomplished this obstruction of justice by falsely claiming that the judicially-approved return never arrived from the county to the Secretary of State’s office.) Later, the state’s highest court held members of the state canvassing board in contempt of court for this conduct, and it was quite a scandal in the state. New York adopted a new constitution in 1894 that attempted, not entirely successfully, to reduce the role of partisanship in the counting of ballots. In any event, these subsequent proceedings did not undo the successful partisan theft of the state senate that had occurred based on the combined outcome of these two disputed seats.

As we watch events unfold this year concerning the unsettled control of the state senate in New York, and the several elections on which that control depends, let’s hope that the current resolution contains nothing like the ugliness that afflicted the episode of 1891.

This Morning’s View

As I look over the undecided statewide races, this is what emerges for me this morning:

Connecticut is the only state that I would label as “yellow alert” so far, using my alert system, given that litigation has already occurred to extend the polling hours in Bridgeport, and more litigation is anticipated.

Otherwise, the processes are proceeding as they should—my “green” category.

Colorado potentially deserves a “blue” because of the Denver Post’s report of the large number of uncounted provisional ballots that could affect the outcome. I can’t yet tell whether any of the other states (besides Alaska) similarly deserve “blue” rather than “green” status. The key difference in my mind between “green” and “blue” is that provisional ballots by definition have an uncertain eligibility status and need eligibility review before being counted. The mere fact that some ballots, like absentees, still need to be counted is not enough to shift a state from green to blue. UPDATE: The Denver Post has called the Senate race for Bennet.

For a similar reason, Alaska deserves a “blue” since the write-in ballots need to be removed. I don’t think Alaska deserves a yellow based on the previous litigation, since it was resolved without apparently affecting the result. If there is new litigation, that would convert Alaska back to yellow.

Another interesting part of the narrative: the states with the three big recounts of the 2000s — Florida, Washington, Minnesota — all have undecided statewide races at the moment (although that might change quickly with Florida–UPDATE: Florida is, indeed, settled with a concession from the Democrat). These states can show that they specifically have improved their processes, after having been put under the microscope recently.

Finally, with respect to all the undecided races, these states have an opportunity to be “laboratories of democracy,” to invoke the famous Brandeis phrase. It will be interesting to watch how the New England states differ in handling their close races. The same holds with a side-by-side comparison of Oregon and Washington. The Midwest can compare Minnesota and Illinois–states with very different rules and political cultures.

Close Elections Are Healthy – If We Trust the Refs

On Election Day, as we contemplate the potential process of resolving races “too close to call” tonight, let’s not jump to any premature conclusion that there were voting issues. Just because a race is too close to call is not an indication there are any problems. The increased use of absentee and provisional ballots in the past decade means we have to sometimes wait for these ballots to be counted before a winner can be declared. And, a recount is a process, not a problem. After a recount is conducted, if there is litigation, that is when we begin to become concerned.

Folks have been quoting the Election Administrators’ Prayer lately: “Lord, Let This Election Not Be Close.” You can understand why: there are widespread predictions of significant statewide races—U.S. Senate or gubernatorial—that could be close enough to require recounts.

While we wait for the early returns that will either bear out or refute these predictions, it is worth keeping the following points in mind:

First, a recount is a process, not a problem. The mere fact that an election requires a recount is, by itself, not a bad sign at all. All it means is that the particular election was extremely competitive, a sign of a vibrant democracy. This point especially applies to statewide races, which necessarily involve the state’s entire electorate and are not complicated by the potential problem of gerrymandering. (In other words, one close congressional race in a state with ten or twenty congressional districts is not necessarily a good sign at all.)

A recount means that the two top vote-getting candidates were almost equally successful in appealing to the average voter who, going into the campaign, was open to persuasion from both sides. Democracy at work. Recounting the ballots is just an indication that the legal system considers elections important enough to take the time and effort to double-check the results, in an effort to make sure that they are correct.

Second, before there can be a recount, it is necessary to complete the initial count. The public is starting to get used to the fact that we don’t always have a complete initial count of all ballots cast in an election on Tuesday night, after the polls close. Two developments over the last decade have accentuated this tendency. One, the existence of provisional ballots, mandated by the Help America Vote Act of 2002, which give voters an opportunity to cast a ballot even if there is question about their eligibility. Because it takes at least a few days to verify whether or not these provisional ballots are indeed eligible for counting, it is impossible to declare a winner in an election where there are enough provisional ballots to conceivably make a difference. Two, as more states increasingly rely on absentee voting—and as they permit absentee ballots to arrive after the polls close as long as they are postmarked by election day—these last-arriving absentee ballots can also make a decisive difference in the outcome.

But neither of these developments are a sign of a malfunction in the election system. On the contrary, there are expected and appropriate byproducts of the policy choices to require provisional ballots and to permit election day postmarking of absentee ballots. If and when the public hears that a statewide race is “too close to call” because of yet-to-be-counted provisional and absentee ballots, the public should not immediately jump to the conclusion that something must be wrong and that there is a danger of the electoral will being nullified in the ballot-counting process. Instead, by itself, the announcement that “calling the race” requires waiting for the counting of these ballots is a sign of the system working properly—and that democracy is capable of identifying a winner when the electorate is closely split between the two leading candidates.

Of course, waiting to start a recount until all the provisional and absentee ballots have been counted initially does delay the process of identifying the winner for at least a couple of weeks. A public tired of a long season of campaign ads, as well as perhaps several weeks of early voting, may be anxious for a result in a major statewide race. Still, even more than answer, the public wants the count to be correct, and thus the public will be patient for the results of a recount as long as it remembers that the recount itself is not a sign of the system going awry, but an integral part of the system itself in order to properly handle the exceptionally close races.

Third, the commotion of the candidates and their supporters is not a sign of system weakness. We can be sure that, where there is a recount, there will be a lot of noise coming from both camps in an effort to sway public opinion towards one side or the other. This noise will include allegations of improprieties and irregularities, as well as pious comments about “counting all the votes” or “the need to bring closure to the election” (you can easily guess which side will say which, depending on who is ahead after the initial count). But the public would do well to filter out this noise and focus instead on the statement of the officials responsible for conducting the recount and bringing the election to a conclusion.

Consider the analogy of the noise among the crowd in a stadium at an important sporting event. If the game has gone into overtime, and a championship is at stake, of course the fans on both sides will be shouting. They are excited and rooting for their team. In the heat of the moment, they may even shout invectives at the referees. But observers who are not particularly partial to one team or the other—or even fans who are when they get a chance to calm down—can recognize if the refs are basically officiating the game fairly. And if they keep their eyes on the refs as they watch the end of the game, they know that all the noise in the stands from the fans on both sides won’t make a difference to the propriety of the outcome. The game will be fair, whatever the noise, because of what happens on the field, not in the stands.

There are different ways to express this key point. ALLEGATIONS of improprieties do not by themselves prove the EXISTENCE of improprieties. Or, as I like to say: in the context of elections at least, where there is smoke does NOT necessarily mean there is fire.

The candidates and their most ardent supporters have the incentive to “make allegations first, attempt to substantiate them later.” The public as a whole, however, should not be bamboozled by these charges. Wait and see what the refs have to say about them—and see if the refs conduct themselves properly, in a way that makes the competition a fair one.

This brings us to our most important point.

Fourthif there is litigation over the outcome of an election, watch for whether the judges agree or disagree about what the result should be under the law.

The existence of lawsuits over the counting of ballots after the polls close is analytically distinct from the existence of a recount, and it is very much worth keeping this distinction in mind as events unfold. Unlike recounts, lawsuits are something of a warning sign. It does mean that one side or the other thinks there have been problems that are potentially outcome-determinative—not merely a close vote that deserves recounting.

Remember, of course, that allegations of problems are just allegations—unless and until a court accepts them as proven facts based on adequate evidence. The filing of a lawsuit is just a formal form of alleging improprieties. The mere filing does not prove them true. Moreover, candidates and their attorneys are quicker to file lawsuits in recent years than in the past, and thus a kind of discount factor can reasonably be applied to the mere filing of a lawsuit in the aftermath of balloting.

If there is this kind of lawsuit, it all comes down to how the judiciary handles it. If several judges look at the lawsuit, at both the trial and appellate levels, and especially if the judges who do so come from different political backgrounds, and they all reach the same conclusion that the lawsuit lacks merit, then the public essentially should treat the result as if the lawsuit never happened. In other words, it was just a very close election; one side tried to prevail by going to court, but they couldn’t make it happen. The system worked. The outcome can be trusted. The situation is essentially equivalent to a recount without a lawsuit at all.

If conversely the judges all agree that the lawsuit HAS merit, then the situation is somewhat different, but not critically alarming. The fact that the lawsuit was correct in alleging problems in the vote-counting process means, regrettably, that there WERE problems that required the court’s attention. It would have been better, obviously, if there hadn’t been the problems in the first place. But if the judges, regardless of their political backgrounds, all agree what the problems were and what should be done to remedy then, then the public can be confident that the election system has well-working judicial “safety-value” to protect the system from problems that can (and, again regrettably, do) arise. The public can trust the outcome of the election in this situation—indeed, more so than if the judiciary had not acted to remedy the problem.

It is only when the judges split in their rulings that we have cause for anxiety. At the very least, a split among judges means that the law or evidence was unclear and thus it was possible for judges to go either way. In this situation, we can’t completely trust the results of the election, even if the judges acted in good faith to the best of their judicial abilities, because how do we know which judicial position was the correct one? If one good-faith judicial position says Candidate A should win the election given the law and evidence, but the other good-faith judicial position says Candidate B should win given the same law and evidence, then by definition the election is being decided by the judges and not just the voters. Moreover, there is inevitably some arbitrariness to this split judicial decision, no matter how well-reasoned both good-faith judicial positions are articulated. How come there were more judges who adopted the one point of view rather than the other? The other candidate would have won this important election if it happened that more judges adopted the alternative good-faith position. That luck-of-the-draw is inevitably unsettling to an electoral system and in some basic sense inconstant with the democratic idea that the voters themselves should determine the outcome of the election.

Of course, the situation is even worse—much worse—if the split among the judges tracks their differing political backgrounds. If Democratic judges rule for Democratic candidates and Republican judges rule for Republican candidates, as disturbingly happens from time to time, then there is no trusting the result. In this situation, the litigation neither validates nor corrects the result of the recount (or initial count), but simply indicates that partisan judicial fiat determines which side prevails. If a system of election integrity monitoring had a set of “alert levels” comparable to those for terrorist warnings, this situation of a partisan split among the judges responsible for deciding litigation over the counting of ballots would qualify for the highest Red Alert level.

But here on Election Day, as we contemplate the potential process of resolving races “too close to call” tonight, let’s not jump to any premature conclusion that we are going to have anything like this kind of Red Alert situation. Let’s hope instead that the process unfolds just as it is supposed to: with the counting of provisional and absentee ballots and the conduct of recounts, if necessary. In the absence of any litigation, there wouldn’t be the need for an heightened alert level. But even if litigation occurs, adjust the alert level only to yellow until we see how the judges handle it. If they split, but not along partisan lines, that warrants an orange-level alert. Let’s save Red Alert for a partisan judicial split. If we do end up seeing it, then let’s call it out: Red Alerts do deserve dramatic attention. But let’s be sophisticated and nuanced enough to be able to distinguish those situations that deserve Red Alert from those that do not.